Outline:
1st Introduction to the
difficulty
2nd Characteristics of the
individual order types
3rd The distinction of
different systems of order
4th The aim suitability of
the individual order types
5th On the pathology of the
order types
1st Introduction to the
difficulty
The
primary task of a system of order is the coordination of individual decisions.
There is a need for coordination wherever a number of individuals form a
community. This applies initially to market-based systems in which the
individual enterprises and households themselves decide on how they use their
material resources. It stands to reason without more ado that the individual
plans need a mutual coordination.
However,
coordination is also needed in a state planned economy. Here the economic decisions shall emanate from a central plan of the
State. But coordination is here also necessary for two reasons. On the one
hand, it would exceed the abilities of an otherwise all-powerful dictator if he
tried to make all the pending economic decisions of a national economy,
composed of more than a handful of citizens, alone. He requires a bureaucracy
consisting of a variety of bureaucrats, and their extent is larger the larger the
size of the national economy is, for which a central plan is to be drawn up.
A
bureaucracy consists of a multitude of superordinate and subordinate entities,
even the central authority is formed by several people, and the dictator who
controls the community is only in some circumstances present in this
bureaucracy.
However,
coordination is necessary in a state planned economy generally also because,
even in a very tight planned economy, the individual citizens have to be
granted certain rights of freedom, which in turn require coordination. Only in
an ideal-typical form of a state centralised administration economy will all
the forthcoming decisions be transferred to the headquarters, and the
individual enterprises and households are only recipients of orders of
the headquarters.
There
are mainly two reasons why individual decisions need to be coordinated. A first
reason for a need for coordination lies in the fact that almost all decisions
of an individual have external and primarily negative effects which trigger a
conflict of interests. On the one hand, the material resources are scarce and
this means that to the extent that the one individual appropriates a larger
part of the resources, fewer resources are available for the other individuals.
On the other hand, the activities of an individual often have direct effects on
the field of interest of the other individuals, for example, when the
cultivation and use of an individual causes numerous annoyances such as noise,
view hindrance, etc. for the owner of a neighbour property.
A second
reason why the activities of single individuals have to be coordinated is that
the economic tasks in a modern society are mostly addressed collaboratively. In
general, households do not produce by themselves for their own need of economic
goods; rather, enterprises are formed in which individual goods are produced
together.
At the
same time, the individual enterprises and households specialise in specific
activities and goods, the one produces the one good, the other one another
good. Through this specialisation and division of labour, productivity
increases enormously, and on average, much more goods are available to all
individuals, than if everyone made the attempt to produce all alone for his own
needs.
However,
such a division of labour requires a wide range of coordination. On the one
hand, the individual activities within an enterprise must be coordinated. On
the other hand, the individual is only ready for such a specialisation if he can
rely on the fact that he can acquire all other goods of his need in exchange
with the goods produced by him.
An
economic order determines the aims to be pursued in detail, the means
by which these aims are addressed, and the bodies to which certain tasks
are assigned. The individual systems of order differ in the reply of each of
these three basic questions.
A market
economy system is characterised especially by the fact that in principle it is
free to every household and enterprise how to use its resources. In a state
planned economy, however, the use of resources is determined by the state.
2nd Characteristics of the
individual order types
On the
one hand, the coordination of individual decisions is usually achieved thereby
that the single individuals receive information which is necessary in
order to carry out the mutual adaption of the planning bodies; on the other hand occur incentives including
sanctions that ensure that the individuals behave according to this
information.
An entrepreneur
needs firstly information on how large the demand for the goods produced by him
is at alternative prices, the quality of goods that consumers are asking, the
number of competitors who produce this good or related goods, at which prices
the competing entrepreneurs offer these goods, and so on and so forth.
However,
in order that the entrepreneur acts in accordance with this information, it
must be ensured that the entrepreneur maximises his profit precisely when he
aligns his production with the wishes of the consumers and that a production
orientation which disregards these needs is penalised with losses. In general,
it can be assumed that precisely these incentives emanate from a full
competition between entrepreneurs.
Information
can be distinguished firstly according to whether they are of normative nature
or explicative nature. Normative information is present when the
individual parties are informed of how they are ought to behave. So receives,
for example, a production manager in a state planned economy instructions from
his superordinate authority about the goods and quantities he has to produce.
Information
of a quite different kind is present when an entrepreneur comes to know in a
market economy which goods and what quantities he can possibly sell at certain
alternative prices. This information
differs not only therein that no instructions are given here, but that it is
only informed about the possibilities, that no instructions are placed on the
persons concerned. As a rule, explicative information is acquired out of
individual initiative.
A second
distinctive feature of possible information lies in the possible bundling
of the information. Information can be given weakly bundled; the necessary
steps are individually listed and described. On the other hand, the bundling
can be so strong that the information consists only of a symbol, so that
the communication of this symbol is sufficient to communicate the necessary
information to the addressee.
A strong
bundling of the information takes place e.g. in a monetary system in comparison
to the pure exchange economy. In the framework of a monetary system, all goods
are evaluated with prices, and the indication of the prices is sufficient in
order to make a clear ranking of the individual goods. In a market economy,
most of the decision-relevant information can be assessed in monetary terms.
In a
similar way, democratic electoral systems are working with a strong bundling.
The individual parties may differ so much according to the most different
criteria; in the end, the number of votes decides alone who will be the winner
of the elections. Also here, all politically relevant factors of influence can
thus be expressed finally in proportion of votes.
The
bureaucratic system, in contrast, is characterised by a very weak bundling of
information. Many laws and ordinances define and describe precisely how the
subordinates ought to behave. Similarly, a negotiation system operates with a
large amount of information. In order to find out which negotiating position a
trade union has reached against the employer, it is necessary to obtain a lot
of information. A single reference value is generally not enough to provide the
negotiators with sufficient information.
A trade union
negotiator must be informed, for example, of the productivity of the workforce,
the profit situation of the entrepreneurs, the bindingness
of the orders and the material consequences for the event that the goods can
not be delivered on time because of a strike, in order to be able to take
appropriate decisions on wage claims and threat of strike.
If we
combine both distinctive features (strong / weak bundling, normative /
explicative) we get four different types of information acquisition:
Firstly,
the information of an order system can be strongly bundled and of a normative
nature. An important example of this first type of information acquisition is
the traffic lights. The system of the traffic lights regulates the right of way
at crossroads only by the colours: red, yellow and green. Further information is not needed to clearly determine
who currently has the right of way and who has to stop.
Secondly,
information can be strongly bundled and of explicative nature. As mentioned
above, such type of information is present in the field of money economy, but
also in the electoral system. The price determines what goods are bought, just
as the voting conditions decide who is to be given power in a democracy.
Thirdly,
we know normative information systems with weak bundling. Each law and
regulation corresponds to this information type. An ordinance, for example,
regulates very detailed what the dos and don'ts are for certain individuals.
Fourthly,
we know the information type, which is only weakly bundled and of explicative
nature. We have already mentioned as an example the negotiations of the
collective bargaining partners; here, quite a lot of information is exchanged
between the negotiating partners.
Let us
turn to the second characteristic of coordination: the incentives. Here, we can
distinguish firstly between positive and negative incentives.
Positive incentives are characterised by the fact that they reward the desired
activities, whereas negative incentives, on the other hand, sanction (penalise)
actions which are undesirable. A positive incentive would be, for example, a
premium; a negative incentive would be a fine.
Secondly,
we can distinguish the incentives according to which mental authority they
address, whereby material interest, conscience or reputation in the community
can be addressed. Combining these two characteristics, we obtain a total of six
possible types of incentives.
An
incentive can be addressed firstly to the material interest and be of a
positive nature: each price reduction is an incentive for the buyer to ask for
more of the concerned good, just as price increases give the sellers an
incentive to produce and offer more of this product.
Secondly,
price variations represent, however, material negative incentives at the same
time. The same price reduction, which gives the buyer a positive incentive,
causes the producer to produce less of this good; and the same price increase,
which encourages the producer to produce more of a good, causes the buyer of
this good to demand less.
Thirdly,
we take the case of a positive incentive which shall promote the social
prestige. An example would be a medal which is awarded to a citizen therefore
that he stood up for the community; the bestowals of orders gives an incentive
to the citizens to do more for the community.
Fourthly,
a public defamation represents a negative incentive which addresses the social
reputation of the defamed: single citizens are punished by the defamation for
having shown an undesired behaviour. This way they are to be deterred from the
unwanted behaviours (e.g. the drug consumption).
Of this
kind of defamation, however, those forms are to be distinguished which are
exercised against people with certain inherent characteristics, for example the
defamation of foreigners, which are, for example, defamed by their skin colour.
Since these features can not be removed, they do neither present a real
deterrence. Of course, such defamation often takes place in order to impel the
persons concerned to leave the country.
Fifthly,
a positive incentive that addresses to conscience takes place, for example,
when the citizens are asked to buy predominantly those goods produced in their
own country.
A final,
sixth incentive, which is of a negative nature and is directed at the
conscience of the parties involved, is present, for example, at the appeals for
moderation of the politicians. For example, in the context of the Concerted
Action, the collective bargaining partners were asked to decide only wage
increases which are not higher than the wage guidelines established by the
State. Because of the tariff autonomy applicable in the FRG, it was not
possible to force the bargaining partners to such a behaviour which promotes
monetary stability. It was therefore
appealed to the social conscience (the social responsibility) of trade unions
and employers to refrain from any wage increases that could endanger monetary
stability.
However,
the coordination performance of an order system depends not only on the type of
information and the incentives. Coordination requires always a mutual
adaptation of the participants and this adaptation differs, among other things,
of how fast and how differentiated it can be reacted to changes. Here, a
distinction can be made between a temporal, functional and personal degree
of differentiation.
In terms
of time, very different periods can elapse before adaptation to the data
changes is possible at all. Let us take the market in which, at least in
principle, an adaptation of one's own behaviour to data changes (e.g. price
increases) is possible immediately after the occurrence of the data change. If
a household finds out that the prices of certain vegetable varieties have
drastically increased and if it is appropriate for a household to consume other
vegetable varieties, the household may carry out this adjustment immediately
after the price change.
Of
course, delays in the adjustment are to be expected in the market sometimes.
Thus prevent cancellation periods the immediate reduction in the demand for the
labour force, at which wage increases have occurred. Cancellation periods,
however, represent already corrections of the market, which were introduced
subsequently due to political aims. There are, however, also adaption delays
which are in the nature of the production process.
If an
enterprise has acquired a production plant which allows production for a number
of years, it is not advantageous in the case of price reductions of another
production plant to immediately dismantle the old plant and purchase a new
plant which, however, performs approximately the same function. An enterprise
will generally only acquire the new, cheaper or technically better plant if the
service life of the existing plant has largely expired.
Let us
take as a counterexample the electoral processes within the framework of a
state democracy. It is usually voted at intervals of four to five years. If
within this legislative period changes are made which, from the point of view
of the voters, require a different composition of the government, the electors
can generally carry out this change only after the end of the legislative
period. Thus, a very much longer period elapses here, until it can be reacted
to the data changes.
Of
course there are also exceptions to this rule. In the case of particularly
drastic events, certain constitutions provide that a new election may also be
made prematurely; or the government sees itself impelled to resign prematurely
due to exceeding discontent in the population, and thus pave the way for new
elections. In this case, the delay period would then be reduced. Despite these
exceptions in the electoral process and in the markets, however, it can be
assumed that in economic systems, it can be reacted much faster to data changes
than in political electoral systems. The temporal degree of
differentiation of a market system is much larger than that of a political
electoral system.
Secondly,
the depth of adaptation can also differ in functional regards from one
order system to another. Adaptation to data changes has a different result,
depending on whether many or few alternatives are under consideration. Let us
first take the example of politics and assume a majority election system, in
which predominantly two parties compete with each other. If a voter is
dissatisfied with the policy of the current government, then he has merely the
possibility to change over to the opposition party at the next election.
Every
party composes in their election program a combination of solutions of
different problem areas. It is quite possible that an individual voter prefers
the economic policy and cultural policy of party A, but the social and foreign
policy of party B; nevertheless he has to decide for one party and thus accept
the solution bundle offered by this party.
If we
have a proportional representation system, the choice options of the voter are
somewhat greater, in general he can choose between several parties; however,
the restriction remains, that he must decide for a solution bundle of one
party.
The
choice options of a consumer in a market system are generally different. Here,
he is not forced at adaptation processes to choose between a few bundles of
goods. He can, in principle, decide freely what kind of good he chooses at
every single good he is demanding; the fact that he has decided to buy organic
food is not compelling him to make a certain choice, for example, at furniture.
Of
course, it is conceivable that certain goods compilations are offered for
ideological reasons or for fashion reasons; whoever prefers organic food will,
for reasons of fundamental considerations, favour also, for example, energy
types which are obtained from renewable energy resources. But here, too, one
will have to assume that market systems as a whole offer a larger number of
alternatives than political electoral systems. The functional degree of
differentiation of the markets is greater than the differentiation of political
systems.
Differences
in the order systems result thirdly also in the personnel degree of
differentiation. On markets are offered individual goods, but in political
systems are offered collective goods. The fact that the one individual has
decided for the good A does not force the other individuals in market-economy
systems to choose also the good A. In the market, the decisions of the single
individuals are basically independent of each other.
Of
course, decisions of one individual also influence the decisions of others. The
fact that an individual asks for a particular good increases the price and by
the price the demand decision of the other individuals is affected. In
addition, there are efforts, for example by fashion, to influence the demand of
individual consumers in such a way that all individuals demand preferably
similar goods.
But here
it is less about incentives which emerge from the economic subsystem than
rather about the influences of the cultural subsystem. Nevertheless, the
individual decisions in the legal sense are independent of one another; the
individual can very well defy these influences and thus not orient oneself to
general fashion.
In political
systems, on the other hand, the services are offered principally as collective
goods which benefit the entire citizenship, or at least a large part, the
individual does not have the possibility to consume another collective good
than his fellow citizens; he can strive, by influencing the politicians, for
that collective goods of his choice are offered, but in these efforts he only
has success if a majority of the voters also prefers these goods.
Continuation follows!