Outline:
01st
Growth theory, a sufficient foundation?
02nd
The main determinants of growth
03rd
The importance of natural resources
04th
The quantitative increase of the quantity of labour
05th
The improvement of the quality of labour
06th
Intensive growth and labour input
07th
Capital and post-Keynesian growth theory
08th
Capital and neoclassical growth theory
09th
Savings promotion versus investment promotion
10th
Economic growth and capital structure
11th
The role of technical progress
12th
Stagnation on account of a too low demand?
01st Growth
theory, a sufficient foundation?
The
traditional growth theory is limited to the question under which conditions a
balanced growth can be expected. A balanced growth presupposes here that both
demand and supply of goods have the same growth rate, so that at least if we
assume a balance of supply and demand in the first period of consideration, no
imbalances are to be expected in the following periods.
Although
this condition may be indispensable to enable lasting trouble-free growth; a
growth theory can only fulfil its tasks if the question is answered, on which
determinants it depends, whether, and possibly how high, the growth rate turns
out. Thus, we shall find out what are the causes for the changes in the growth
rate.
02nd The
main determinants of growth
Starting
point of our following analysis shall be the framework data of Walter Eucken.
According to this, the economic activity and thus also the economic growth
depends on a total of 6 data: which include:
• the natural resources including the
land,
• the labour force,
• the capital,
• the technical knowledge,
• the requirements structure and
• the legal and institutional order.
It
is now the production function which indicates the connections between input
and output. The output, thus the production volume (X), depends on the use of
all production factors, hence the number of employees or working hours (A),
furthermore on the used amount of natural resources (B), including the
properties required for production, as well as on the amount of capital (K)
required for production. The formula applies:
• X: produced quantity of goods
• A: labour input
• B: use of natural resources
• K: use of capital
At
times the material production factors land and capital are aggregated, so that
then the product quantity can be understood as a function of labour and capital
in a broader sense:
The
role of technical progress indicates the struc-tural
parameters of the production function. It de-pends on the technology applied in
each case, how many units of goods can be produced with a given portfolio of
labour and capital, respectively how much labour and capital is needed to
produce a certain amount of goods.
In
the production theory we generally assume very specific qualities of a
production function, as de-scribed by Cobb and Douglas in the scope of
empirical investigations. Accordingly, the production functions have the
following structure:
The
general growth parameter indicates which productivity features help to improve
all factors, while the alpha parameter relates only to the labour factor and
indicates by what percentage the examined good increases when the factor labour
increases by a percentage.
It is one of the peculiarities of this
Cobb-Douglas production function that the potencies of labour and capital
always add up to one. In material terms, this structure means that by an increase
of one of the two production factors, the yield growth decreases with increasing
production of goods, whereas if both production factors are increased to the
same extent, the increase in yield growth remains constant, that is the
marginal level product equals to one.
Now
we generally distinguish between a neutral, a labour-saving and a
capital-saving technical pro-gress. The neutral
progress is characterised by the fact that productivity gains are allocated to
both (all) production factors, while at a labour-saving (capital-saving)
progress the same production quantity as before requires less labour (less
capital).
The
classics of economic theory assumed a some-what different production function.
While at the assumption of a Cobb-Douglas production function the law of
decreasing marginal returns applies to all work assignments, it is assumed in
the classical production function that initially the marginal return even
increases with increasing factor input and the marginal return decreases only
after exceeding a critical production level. The classical production function
is backed by the notion that at given technology there is a very particular
factor input ratio at which an optimum can be achieved, while any deviation
from this optimal input ratio (both an increase and a decrease) leads to a
suboptimal production.
Demand
also determines growth. Initially, the production function shows only which
quantity of goods could be produced. In a market economy, however, only the
types of goods and quantities of goods are produced, for which there is a need
indicated by demand. Goods that are not in demand are not even produced. In
this respect, the actually realised growth rate of the domestic product always
depends on the growth rate of demand. For growth to come about, both the
possibilities for production as well as the development of demand are necessary
preconditions.
Whether
and to what extent economic growth is possible depends ultimately also on the
in each case realised institutional order. An economic order determines which
values are to be realised. From the catalogue of the values to be preserved, it
can then be deduced which courses of action are necessary to preserve these
values and which other actions endanger these values. An order also consists
always of the incentives to bring about the required behaviour, whether it be
the punishment that prevents the economic agents from nevertheless committing
the prohibited actions or be it that the desired actions are rewarded.
03rd The
importance of natural resources
In
ancient times, raw materials and natural transport routes were the most
important basis for economic growth.
With
industrialisation, the importance of natural resources for growth declined.
Natural raw materials can be replaced by artificial ones. The fertility of the
soil can be improved by manuring. Artificial transport infrastructure can be
built.
Nowadays,
nature has a greater role to play again: in the first place, we have the
problem of environmental pollution: industrial production causes environmental
damages, due to which the number and severity of natural disasters is
increasing.
Thereby,
the problem of scarce raw materials is addressed, too: Due to the scarcity of
raw materials, arose the demand for sustainability; to leave sufficient
resources of raw materials for subsequent generations. This occurs partly by
recycling, partly by developing new resources such as e.g. the alternative
energy from solar and wind power or the biomass.
04th The
quantitative increase of the quantity of labour
Now,
let us ask to what extent the production factor labour (A) influences the
output (X), the domestic product. Here, it must be differentiated between a
purely quantitative and a qualitative relationship. This differentiation
applies equally to both input and output. In principle, we must assume that an
improvement in the quality of the labour force leads to an increase in quality
in the product as well.
But
it is also conceivable that a mere increase in labour units leads to improved quality
of the products. Suppose that because new labour force is hired in production,
and therefore each individual employee is responsible for fewer products, just
therefore he can draw his attention to the remaining quantities of goods, so
that less waste is produced, and the remaining goods show fewer defects and in
this way the quality of the goods is increased.
Similarly,
however, can the quantity of the products be increased also conversely by an
improved quality of labour. Accordingly, it is conceivable that due to a new
process the quality of the goods to be produced can be improved significantly,
but that at this process new machines must be purchased, which require special
training of the qualified labourers. However, the increased production in this
case is actually rather to be attributed to the changed technology, which in
turn presupposes an improved quality of labour.
We
begin the analysis by trying to increase or also improve the quality of
production by increasing the use of the factor labour.
Numerous
determinants influence the labour input. The number of available working hours
is determined:
•
by the birth and death rate; more children are born or fewer workers die before
they leave the labour market. Here, it shall be considered, however, that the
children born today enter the labour market only after about 20 years, so that
for this reason the number of employees increases strongly delayed.
•
by the net immigration (the difference between immigration and emigration); in
overall terms, more people are available in an economy if more young and
employable people immigrate than emigrate at the same time.
•
by the age of entry and retirement; here, the number of labour force is
increased thereby that workers either enter the labour market sooner or retire
later as hitherto from the labour market. However, it must be considered here
that in the reality the reverse processes take place mostly, that due to the
extension of the training period, the entry into working life takes place only
at a higher age or retirement age occurs earlier.
•
by the change in the employee rate of the labour force; furthermore, the number
of workers can also be changed thereby that previously self-employed persons
lose their self-employment, in this case the number of employees increases, or
else that people who were previously considered as employees, are active as
self-employed now. Of course, the number of employees can also be changed
thereby that employees give up their working life at all, thus e.g. become homeless
or cannot be gainfully employed due to health reasons.
• by the extent of unemployment; if
employees are willing to work but cannot find employment, then the total number
of available working hours is less than it could be without unemployment. In
this respect, a successful reduction of unemployment can help to increase the
number of available labour force.
•
by the increase or decrease of part-time employ-ees;
while the changes in the factor labour listed above have changed the number of
labour force, can the amount of labour input also be changed by changing the
average number of hours worked. We must always expect that some of the
employees do not work full-time. Now, as the proportion of part-time workers
changes, this change also affects the average work time per employee. The same
applies if employees must work short time due to a decline in the demand for
goods.
•
by a possible increase in the effective working time; but the same effect can
be expected even if the effective working time changes, for example, if the
contractually provided working hours in the collective agreements are
shortened. However, it must be reckoned with the possibility that effective
working time may remain unaffected by these changes in the collective
agreements, if employees increase their above the scale working time in form of
overtime working hours by the same amount. Of course, an increase or even a
reduction in overtime hours can vary in the scope of effective working hours,
naturally also regardless of tariff changes.
•
by the reduction of the sickness rate and the accident frequency; illness and
accident can lead to a temporary incapacity for work and thus reduce the number
of available working hours. In the event of accidents, the ability to work may
be sometimes limited permanently. Advances in medicine can eventually lead to
an increase in the available working hours again.
05th The
improvement of the quality of labour
Let
us now turn to the possibilities to improve the output by raising the quality
of labour. The quality of labour can be increased primarily by two sets of
measures:
On
the one hand, by education policy: By allowing a larger part of young people
the access to secondary schools and universities, the labour productivity can be
increased. Sometimes occurs unemployment to unemployed workers simply because
technological advances can lead to production facilities that require an ever
higher educational level from the labour force. By qualification of the
previously unskilled workers can be prevented in this way that these become
unemployed due to technical progress.
On
the other hand, by mobility policies: The in-crease in mobility means that
workers can increasingly be deployed where they achieve the highest
productivity. It can often be assumed that individual employees have not yet
found the workplace that matches their abilities at their first job. If there
were no possibilities to a job change for the individual employees, their labour
productivity would be suboptimal permanently. By changing jobs, it can be
achieved that labour productivity increases in the long run, even if each
change entails adjustment costs.
06th
Intensive growth and labour input
In
our previous considerations, we had dealt with the extensive growth. We started
from a production function and asked for the determinants why the output could
be changed for the better due to an increased or also improved employment of
labour. But as we have already pointed out, the economic growth is seen first
and foremost as a benchmark of macroeconomic welfare.
However,
the welfare of a population depends less on extensive than on intensive growth.
A population does not become richer automatically when the domestic product
increases due to more available workers. The domestic product has risen here,
but so has the number of people to whom this product must be divided. The
individual citizens achieve a welfare gain only if either the per capita income
or the labour productivity increases. Therefore, let us turn now to the question
of which relations exist between labour input and intensive growth.
To
this, let us look at the individual determinants of labour input, namely
firstly the population growth caused by immigration (B). The domestic product
is rising (Y); it is unclear, however, whether the per capita income will
increase, too.
The
per capita income is calculated by the ratio of domestic product and
population: Y/B. With an immigration both sizes, numerator and denominator
rise. Depending on whether the domestic product increases more or less than the
population, the per capita income increases or decreases. (figure 2)
Now
we consider secondly the increase in the birth rate and the thereby triggered
population growth. Initially, the supply of workers may decrease, as possibly
more women are only working in their own household and are no longer employed
in an extra-familial occupation. In this case, the per capita income even
declines temporarily, since women are temporarily unemployed before and immediately
after birth. The number of employees and thus also the domestic product is thus
decreasing at the same population size.
But
in the long term, as the children born today will become gainfully employed in
the future, the number of employees and thus the domestic product will increase
again.
As
third reason for intensive growth may an in-crease in working hours be assumed.
With a con-stant number of employees, there is an
increase of the work supply calculated in hours.
But
due to the law of diminishing marginal returns of labour, this leads to a
reduction of labour productivity. The domestic product is rising, but it is
rising less than the number of working hours. Thus, the per capita income
increases, but the productivity of labour decreases at the same time.
Now
- as already mentioned - we generally distinguish between two different yield functions.
The classical theory was based on the following yield function: An increase in
the labour input thus leads initially to an increase not only in the quantities
of goods, but also in the average yield of the labour, since regarding an
optimal factor combination, the labour force is initially present in a too
small an extent. Now, if production continues to rise, then a critical
threshold is finally reached, from which on the product quantity continues to
increase with additional labour input, but the average yield decreases.
This
is based on the idea that there is an optimal input ratio between capital and
labour. If this optimal input ratio (A/K) is given, then the productivity has
reached its maximum value. However, on both sides of this operation ratio,
namely at a higher or a lower labour input, the productivity is lower and thus
suboptimal.
The
exact location of this threshold is of course not in the nature of the factors
of production. Rather, it depends on the type of technical progress, at which
input ratio this optimum is achieved. A change in technology therefore usually
changes the point at which the average yield reaches its optimum.
We
take an example of an enterprise that aims to change the technology in order to
allow certain work steps, hitherto done by workers, to be done by machines,
thereby saving labour. Thus, a new production plant is constructed, which
fulfils this aim as exactly as possible and which requires a very specific
capital investment. This capital investment is thus given by introducing this
new method, and together with the planned factor input ratio for this new production
plant the amount of labour at which this optimum is achieved is then
calculated. (figure 4)
The
type of technical progress is thus, primarily responsible for the development
of labour productivity. We distinguish between neutral, labour-saving and
capital-saving technical progress.
With
neutral technical progress, savings are made in principle at all relevant
production factors. At this, neutral progress is defined differently in the
growth theory. Harrod speaks of neutral progress when capital productivity
remains constant at constant interest rates:
Whereas
for Hicks there is a neutral progress pre-sent when the capital intensity
remains constant with a constant wage-interest ratio:
Finally,
Solow speaks of a neutral technical progress, if labour productivity remains
constant with a constant wage rate:
Furthermore,
it is spoken of a labour-saving tech-nical progress,
whenever the technical progress is mainly only labour saving.
Analogous
to this, it is spoken of capital-saving technical progress, if the savings
relate primarily to the capital investment. It can be assumed that even in this
case the average product of labour can increase, just as with labour-saving
progress also the average product of capital can increase.