Outline:
01st
The long-term commitment of state expenditures
02nd
The slow legislative machinery
03rd
The problem of the budget balance
04th
The federal structure of the state
05th
About the problem of the independence of the central bank
06th
About the economic policy problem of tariff autonomy
07th
The significance of the Council of Economic Experts
08th
Problems of international economic policy
01st
The long-term commitment of state expenditures
We
had previously dealt with the question of the extent to which employment policy
measures were suitable for increasing employment and with the further question
of to what extent it must be expected that these measures would have negative
secondary effects on other economic policy aims. In this chapter, we will now
address the question of which agency should be entrusted with employment policy
tasks.
Here,
too, we must assume that there is a variety of executive agencies which could
possibly implement measures to influence employment positively, e.g. there are
the executive and legislative authorities, there are the government authorities
in the narrower sense and the central bank. Within the government authorities
there are the federal government, the federal states and the municipalities,
and as non-governmental authorities e.g. collective bargaining partners could
be entrusted with certain political tasks such as the obligation to agree only
on wage increases which do not endanger monetary stability.
The
individual agencies differ in the way in which a decision is reached and in the
rights an agency has in order to carry out the tasks entrusted to it. First,
let us look at the activities of the government, where an employment policy
effect can emanate especially from state expenses.
In
the context of economic policy, generally expenditure policy has priority over
fiscal policy. State expenditures, as we have seen in the previous chapters,
have primarily a greater multiplier than taxes.
For
government expenditures is valid:
whereas
for tax revenues is valid:
· Y: domestic product
· GSt: government expenditures
· T: tax revenues
· s: savings propensity
· t: tax rate
A
comparison of the effectiveness of both an increase in government expenditures
as well as a reduction in tax revenues naturally presupposes that we compare an
equal amount (e.g. 1 billion) of changes in government expenditures and tax
revenues with each other, i.e. dGST and dT
are to be set at the same size and this in turn means that the revenue
multiplier is lower by the value of 1 than the expenditure multiplier.
With
government expenditures arise furthermore both primary effects and induced
secondary effects, with taxes arise only the induced secondary effects. Let us
take as an example the case where the state hires more civil servants in period
0 and thus increases government expenditures. The actual primary employment
effect in this case is that the state employed new labour force in the period
0.
Secondary
(and indeed positive) employment effects arise here from the fact that the
additionally employed civil servants spend their income on consumer goods in
the respectively next period and that in this way more consumer goods are
produced and therefore additional labour forces are employed also. This process
continues in the following periods. Since only a certain part of the additional
income is spent on consumer goods, the respectively induced employment
increases are smaller in each period. Thus, this is an infinite series with a
finite value.
Contrary
to this, a reduction in tax revenues in period 0 causes initially no primary
increases in employment at all. Only privately disposable income increases to
the extent to which tax rates are reduced. However, the employment effects
induced in further periods are identical to the secondary employment effects
triggered by increases of government expenditures.
But
government expenditures are for the most part committed on a long-term basis:
This applies particularly to expenditures which are determined by international
treaties, such as defence expenditures, as well as to the contributions to the
European Union. Civil servants are furthermore not cancellable. After all, a
reduction in the social budget for economic policy reasons may possibly
contradict to social policy aims.
A
special role falls to voter-effective expenditures: Politicians tend to spend
predominantly on those expenditures that generate voter gains and to realise
expenditure increases predominantly just before elections. In political
economics, it is assumed that voters forget very quickly what advantages and
disadvantages they gain from the state, so that it is advantageous for
politicians to implement such measures immediately before the elections which
trigger positive effects relatively quickly, while measures that initially
burden the population and only show their positive effects much later are implemented
shortly after the elections.
A
special importance in this context is attached to infrastructure investments:
although infrastructure investments have a greater growth effect in the long
term, they are less perceived by voters since a positive impact on the income
of the voters will only occur in the future.
02nd The
slow legislative machinery
Variations
in taxes are in general only possible due to legislative changes. Government
expenditures, by contrast, are usually decided by ordinance.
The
legislative process is very time-consuming: First, coalition negotiations are
needed between the parties involved in the government, provided that the government
consists of several parties. Sometimes it is necessary to reach agreements with
the interest groups in order to prevent that the implementation of the laws
will be blocked by these groups. Almost every law must be prepared initially at
the administrative level.
After
the legislative draft has been introduced into parliament by the government, it
is discussed in several readings in parliament and partly referred to
subcommittees. In federal states, the laws must also be discussed and passed in
a second chamber (in the FRG in the Bundesrat i.e. Federal Council) provided
that these laws affect the interests of the federal states. Sometimes the
legislative drafts are remitted to the first chamber (in the FRG thus to the
Bundestag i.e. Federal Parliament). Then a mediation committee is often
required to reach a final agreement.
In
the Stabilisation Act of 1967, an attempt was made to reduce these
deficiencies, which are mainly due to a loss of time: According to this,
short-term tax variations are possible by means of ordinances in order to
enable that tax rate changes which are motivated by economic policy can be
carried out more quickly. In this case, the adoption by Parliament will take
place later. In this way it shall be ensured that the laws intervene in the
economic process in due time and help to reduce unemployment.
Furthermore,
there is a necessity for medium-term financial planning. In this way, it shall
be achieved primarily that the state budget remains balanced in the longer
term, i.e. within an economic cycle. This purpose is also served by the
introduction of an economic equalisation reserve.
03rd
The problem of the budget balance
Votes
maximisation leads to an explosion in expenditures if expenditures can be
financed in deficit. Increases in government expenditures lead to welfare gains
for voters, while tax increases are equivalent to a reduction in privately
disposable incomes. The politicians could thus increase their electoral chances
if they were able to raise state expenditures more than the tax revenues that
are needed to finance these expenditures. Exactly this, however, will become
possible if the increases in government expenditures are financed in deficit,
i.e. if they are covered by government debt or by loans from the central bank.
Thus, in a democracy there is a trend towards deficit financing.
Now
we must realise that even if government expenditures are financed in deficit,
the voters will finally have to pay for these increases in government
expenditures. The demand of the state as well as that of private households
always refers to one and the same scarce resource stock. Production factors
used in the production of public goods can no longer be used to produce private
goods, so that regardless of how government expenditures are financed, the
share of private goods decreases to the same extent as the share of public
goods increases.
But
this process is no longer readily apparent to if government expenditures are
financed in deficit. The fact that fewer resources are now available for the
production of private goods impacts in the form of price increases, which are,
however, raised directly by enterprises, although it is of course the state
with the increase in demand for public goods that ultimately triggered these
price increases. However, since price increases are raised visibly by
enterprises and not by the state, the correlation between increases in
government expenditures and price increases for private goods remains largely
hidden to voters.
By
means of a demand for budget compensation, a limitation of expenditures can be
achieved. Only such increases in expenditures will then be possible which are
also accepted by the voters as they agree to the tax increases. But the
question is whether this principle is still valid in the case of
underemployment. According to Keynesian ideas, a deficit leads to an increase
in the domestic product and thus does not lead to a reduction in real income.
Nevertheless, also in this case, the share of individual goods in the domestic
product decreases if the state increases its expenditures and finances this
increase in expenditures in deficit. The right of the voter to decide for
himself by means of the elections how the domestic product shall be divided
among individual goods and collective goods can only be realised if the budget
is balanced.
These
limitations show that the principle of budget balance should never be related
to a short period. If the state is obliged to balance its budget in every
period, including the economic downturn, it can only fulfil this obligation in
times of economic downturn by realising a compensation due to the decrease in
its tax revenues by either raising tax rates or reducing government
expenditures. This is referred to as procyclical fiscal policy. However, this
contributes to a worsening of the recession and should therefore be avoided in
any case.
It
would be wrong to misunderstand the supporters of budget balance as though they
were ever calling for a pro-cyclical policy. A pro-cyclical policy is rejected
equally by both supporters and opponents of Keynesian employment policy. The
difference between the two groups is that supporters of Keynesian policy demand
that the state pursues anti-cyclical policy, i.e. that in times of recession it
increases expenditures in the sense of a "go" or reduces tax
revenues, and in times of economic booms it reduces expenditures in the sense
of a "stop" or raises tax rates.
Such
a stop and go policy, however, is rejected by the opponents of a Keynesian
policy, since in this way particularly the uncertainty of long-term investment
projects increases, and such a policy is therefore detrimental to long-term
growth. Rather, it was necessary for the state to align its expenditures with
long-term aims and ensure budget balance for the entire economic cycle.
04th
The federal structure of the state
Expenditures
and taxes are decided not only by the federal government and the federal
parliament, but also by state parliaments and local councils. But this means
that economy and employment are not only influenced by the fiscal policy
activity of the federal government, but that the fiscal policy behaviour of the
federal states and municipalities also influences the macroeconomic target
figures. It is therefore also not sufficient if only the federal government
aligns its fiscal policy with economic requirements. The federal states and
municipalities must also consider the economic effects of their actions.
This
demand applies in particular because the federal states exert influence on
macroeconomic variables not only by their own financial policies, but rather
also indirectly via the fact that they have to give their approval to many
legislative projects in the Federal Council and can thus counteract the
economic policy of the federal government.
Due
to the different party orientation of the state governments, there is indeed a
danger of an inconsistent economic policy at both federal and state level.
Since the elections to the Federal Parliament and the state parliaments
generally take place at different times, there is a great danger that the
composition of the state parliaments will be different from that of the Federal
Parliament and that therefore often the government in the federal states is
formed by the parties which belong to the opposition in the Federation.
It
is precisely this possibility of a different composition of the Federal
Parliament and the Federal Council that entails the danger that the parties
block each other and that therefore neither the Federal Government nor the
state governments are able to fully realise their aims.
It
is precisely because of these conflicts and inefficiencies that it should be
ensured that the Federal Council can only prevent the submissions of the
Federal Government and the Federal Parliament in cases where the
well-understood interests of the federal states are really at stake. However,
there is always the danger that the representatives of the states may pretend
to represent the interests of the states, but that in practice the opposition
to federal laws arises from different party affiliations.
In
order to ensure that state parliaments and governments align their fiscal
policy with the requirements of economic policy, it was decided in § 18 of the
Stabilisation Act of 1967 to establish a Business Cycle Council in which the
Federation and the states are represented. Furthermore, a limit on credit loans
(§§19-25) is also provided for the states and municipalities. Finally, the
states are required to align their activities expressis
verbis with the macroeconomic aims. (§§ 1, 16)
05th
About the problem of the independence of the central bank
The
responsibility for economic policy lies with the state. However, the success of
governmental fiscal policy depends among others also on monetary policy. For
this reason, most central banks are legally obliged to support the economic
policy aims of the state.
However,
in all larger liberal democratic states there is a division of labour between
the monetary policy of the central bank and the economic policy of government
and parliament. The central bank is entrusted with the task of ensuring a
sufficient supply of money, while governments and parliaments are responsible
for determining government expenditures and tax rates.
Here,
the central bank must, in accordance with the statutes of these financial
institutions, ensure currency stability as the most important aim. This
means, on the one hand, that the price level should be kept as constant as
possible in the internal relationship, thus avoiding inflation. In the external
relationship with other countries, by contrast, it is a matter of ensuring a
considerable stability between the exchange rates of the individual currencies,
since only if exchange rate fluctuations are not too large the risk of foreign
trade will be reduced to such an extent that sufficient enterprises are willing
to engage in international trade at all.
In
this connection, we must consider the fact that, in addition to the general
risks associated with most entrepreneurial decisions, there is an additional
risk in foreign trade that, once the decision is made, currency relations will
be changed, with the consequence that usually profitable businesses become
loss-making businesses. It is clear that in such a case it cannot be expected
that entrepreneurs will be sufficiently willing to incur these additional risks
induced by foreign trade.
This
division of labour between the central bank on the one side and the government
or parliament on the other side is necessary to guarantee the basic aims of any
democracy. Without strict adherence to this division of labour, there would be
the danger that the state and the central bank as a whole would no longer
fulfil the will of the people (the majority of the population).
Let
us first consider a government and a parliament which - contrary to these aims
of monetary stability - could significantly influence the money supply of the
economy. If state politicians were in a position to decide for themselves on
the money supply, there would be a danger that politicians would strive to
finance as much state expenditures as possible by borrowing from the central
bank to finance state expenditures and thus would determine the amount of money
in circulation on their own. We have already seen above that in a
representative democracy, politicians would be able to figure out their
election chances in this way and that voters would no longer be able to decide
for themselves to what extent an increase in the share of public goods (and at
the same time a reduction in the share of individual goods) would increase
their welfare.
But
there are also further justifications for the independence of the central bank:
measures to maintain monetary stability will increase welfare only in the long
term. They are often associated with temporary welfare losses in the short
term, which makes these measures extremely unpopular. If these decisions were
to be taken by the government or parliaments, there would be a danger that
politicians would refrain from such decisions, especially shortly before
elections.
The
independence of the central bank in Germany was also due to further, special
reasons: the war generation lost its assets twice due to inflation, namely
during inflation in the period after the First World War and during the
currency reform at the beginning of the Federal Republic.
06th
The economic policy problem of tariff autonomy
There
is a danger that the standard wage policy of the trade unions will have an
inflationary effect and cause unemployment. The responsibility for economic
policy lies with the state, though. Because of that there emerged a demand for
binding wage guidelines for the collective bargaining partners.
In
the FRG, however, there is constitutionally protected collective bargaining
autonomy. That is why the state has limited itself in the past (e.g. during the
first grand coalition) to measures of 'moral persuasion'.
Thus
K. Schiller introduced the Concerted Action in 1967. It provided for
non-binding orientation data. It was acted on the basis of the principle of
'carrot and stick'.
The
carrot consisted in the participation of the social partners in the Concerted
Action, the stick consisted in the hidden threat to restrict collective
bargaining autonomy in the event of failure. Participants of the Concerted
Action were: the tariff partners and the state. The basis was § 3 of the
Stability Act, which postulated the responsibility of the state for stability.
It
can be shown that a success of a Concerted Action on the labour market can only
be expected in the first rounds. Interest groups may be ready to cut back their
own interests at short notice in times of need. In the long term, however, the
Concerted Action is not able to prevent hereby the danger of inflation arising
from collective bargaining autonomy.
The
reasons for the long-term failure of a Concerted Action are found in the
following facts:
Firstly,
there is the contradiction between the aims of economic policy and structural
policy. The determination of collectively agreed wage rates is primarily
concerned with a structural problem, it is a question of which relations
between wage rates shall be implemented in the individual branches of the
economy.
But
at the counselling in the Concerted Action the only issue is the overall
economic wage level. In the attempt by individual trade unions to improve their
position within the wage structure or even only defend it, disappears the
willingness to renounce this aim merely for reasons of monetary stability and
to be content with a wage in accordance with the wage guidelines. Thus a
collective agreement is concluded at the meso-economic level of the sector, but
wage guidelines apply to the economy as a whole.
Secondly,
there are material disincentives, since an opt-out from the Concerted Action is
materially rewarded. If an individual union forces a higher wage increase
contrary to the wage guidelines of the Concerted Action, then the advantage of
this union wage policy benefits only this one union, while the disadvantages,
which consist in price increases, are borne by all employees, including those
who have adhered to the wage guidelines. This means that those who adhere to
the wage guidelines will be sanctioned and those who break them will be
rewarded. With such disincentives it cannot be expected that the majority of
the trade unions will adhere to the wage guidelines in the long run.
Thirdly,
the official confirmation of wage increases leads to further wage demands. If
the Concerted Action finds that a three-percent wage increase can be absorbed
by the economy, and if therefore this three-percent wage increase is determined
in the wage guidelines, it will no longer be possible for employers to start
collective bargaining with an initial offer of less than 3%.
At
the same time, most unions are pursuing the aim of demanding and asserting
somewhat more in collective bargaining than has already been officially
declared desirable by the government. Otherwise, there would be a danger that
the members would turn away from the trade unions, as they have not achieved
more than what had already been agreed within the framework of the Concerted
Action. Thus, the unions will begin collective bargaining with wage demands
that are considerably higher than the wage guideline.
An
agreement between trade unions and employers presupposes that both sides are
prepared to compromise and therefore make concessions. If, however, the
employers have already started the negotiations with an offer that is actually
at the upper limit, the negotiations will become particularly conflictual. At
the end of the day, the result will usually be a wage that exceeds the wage
guideline.
If
the wage guideline is now based on labour productivity growth, then exceeding
it would be undesirable from a macroeconomic perspective, though. The Concerted
Action was intended precisely to prevent that inflation trends emanate from the
labour market, but this is always the case when wage increases on average
exceed labour productivity growth.
The
attempt to circumvent this difficulty by requiring wage guidelines to be
slightly below productivity growth generally fails because the public hardly
accepts wage guidelines that are below the increase in labour productivity.
07th
The significance of the Council of Economic Experts
The
wage increases that can be absorbed macroeconomically are certainly
interpretable in individual cases. This is because wage increases always
influence a variety of economic policy aims. The trade unions are primarily
concerned with income distribution. If wages are raised more than labour
productivity increases, then either inflationary trends or unemployment are to
be feared, depending on whether the central bank meets the increased need for
money as wage income increases by expanding the money supply or not.
Economic
growth can also be influenced by wage policy, as with wage increases the
wage-interest ratio is changed as well, which itself is responsible again for
the manner of technical progress. Depending on the severity of these side
effects, a different wage guideline may be considered desirable. However, the
assessment of these aims is based on interests.
Thus,
there is a danger that the economic data will be interpreted in a manner that
reflects the interests of industry and the state. Contradictory theories lead
to different positions. The Federal Government represents interests, too.
It
was precisely in order to avoid this conflict of interests that the Council of
Economic Experts was founded, which shall determine the data relevant to the
economic situation on a scientific basis in a way that is independent of
interests. The tasks of the Council of Economic Experts consist:
·
in
the assessment how far the macroeconomic aims have been achieved;
·
in
pointing out erroneous trends and
·
in
recommendations to address these developments.
08th
Problems of international economic policy
A necessity for the coordination of the
individual political executing agencies results also from the international
interrelations of the states: An import of unemployment and inflation via
CB-imbalances is possible if a system of fixed exchange rates is present. If
the price-increase rate abroad is higher than that of the domestic economy,
there occurs a current account surplus:
Within
the framework of Keynesian theory, the current account surplus leads to an
increase in national income (Y) and at full employment to price increases:
By
contrast, in the framework of classical theory, at a current account surplus an
increase in the domestic money supply (M) is to be expected, which will have a
price-increasing effect:
·
P:Ausl/Inl:
price level abroad/domestically
· Y: domestic product
·
P:
price level of goods
·
M:
amount of money in circulation
There
is also an interdependence on the degree of integration of the individual
national economies: the more interrelated the national economies are, the more
is inflation or unemployment abroad transferred to the domestic economy.
Thus,
the following effects result from an expansionary monetary policy abroad: The
interest rate reduction abroad (iAusl) leads to an interest rate
reduction in the interior (iInl) and thus to an economic revival in
the domestic economy:
·
iAusl/Inl:
interest abroad/domestic
· Y: domestic product
An
expansive fiscal policy abroad, by contrast, has the following effects: If the
money supply remains constant, the deficit of the foreign state budget (A-T)Ausl
causes an increase in interest rates abroad (iAusl), which also leads
to increases in interest rates domestically (iInl), thus reducing
demand and along with it the domestic product:
·
A-T:
deficit of the state budget
The
foreign trade relations within Europe were set by different monetary systems in
the period after the Second World War: Initially, monetary policy cooperation
took place within the IMS system by mutually supporting exchange rates, with
the US dollar being the leading currency. Later, in the 1970s, the EMS system
was created, which adhered to the aim of stabilising exchange rates but, unlike
the IMF system, referred the leading currency to an artificially created
monetary unit. Finally, in 1999, the European monetary order was formed with a
single currency, the Euro. The problems associated with this, however, will not
be addressed until the lecture on foreign economic policy.